I’ve just returned a week with the WHO in Geneva, where I was working on tobacco control. The tobacco control lobby have made huge achievements in the last 20 years, managing to turn the tide of tobacco use in many countries and pushing some countries (like Australia) towards the dream of zero tobacco, without criminalizing anyone or directly engaging in prohibition strategies. However in the past 2-3 years the movement has been inflamed by a new controversy that they seem to be handling rather poorly – electronic cigarettes. Debate on what to do about e-cigarettes has been vocal and bitter, with the tobacco control camp dividing on roughly Atlantic lines between two opposing camps: harm reduction and prohibition. On the one hand, the prohibitionists see e-cigarettes as a product that glamorizes smoking and is no less healthy, and they want to control the proliferation of these products before they can get the market purchase that tobacco obtained in the early 19th century. This part of the tobacco control lobby sees them as a potential gateway to cigarette smoking, and thinks they should be punitively controlled from the start. Another part of the tobacco control lobby sees e-cigarettes as an alternative to smoking, and situates them within a harm reduction framework that suggests they could play an important role in moving smokers away from dangerous tobacco. e-Cigarettes are a nicotine delivery system without any of the carcinogenic products of burnt tobacco, and so offer a way for addicted smokers to satisfy their nicotine needs without inhaling carcinogens; from a harm reduction perspective this makes the e-cigarette a very useful tool in tobacco control. The debate is usefully summarized by the British Medical Journal here, with links, and the journal Addiction has a lot to say on the matter.
For what it’s worth, as someone who worked for years in the field of heroin use, I see harm reduction as the absolute best strategy for dealing with drug use, and I think e-Cigarettes provide an excellent tool for steering smokers away from tobacco. Nicotine itself is not a poisonous or carcinogenic substance, and the only reason to object to its consumption is a moralistic opposition to addiction itself. From a harm reduction perspective, such a position is completely nonsensical: if we object to a drug, we should do so purely for its health or social effects, not for the simple fact that it is addictive, and while the health and social effects of smoking tobacco are huge, there is no evidence of any serious negative consequences of vaping.
I would go further and say that vaping isn’t just a neutral thing – it’s potentially hugely beneficial. In the era of smoking bans, there is a huge market for a product that enables people to smoke in public places, cars, and their family home without offending or harming the people around them. Vaping doesn’t just not harm the individual, it enables them to smoke around those of their friends and family who didn’t take up this stupid habit. As quit campaigns, smoking bans and taxes begin to bite, smokers are surrounded by more and more people who don’t smoke, which gives them increasing incentive to drop tobacco. But tobacco is intensely addictive, so they couldn’t – until this technology offered a way to do it. I’ve gamed indoors with players who vape, and it is absolutely a completely innocuous habit. I’ve gamed with smokers too, and in order to not offend the group they have to pause the game to go outside and smoke. The better option is obvious.
In fact, I don’t think I’ve ever met a smoker who wouldn’t vape in such a situation.
About ten years ago I was involved in an evaluation of a sudden heroin shortage in Australia. One of the main lessons of this shortage was that prohibition and harm reduction are strategies that can complement each other. In an environment of strict prohibition, when sudden market disruptions happen, the availability of harm reduction measures can rapidly take people out of the marketplace for the drug and onto safer alternatives. As we ratchet up the pressure on tobacco companies, increasing taxes and making it more and more difficult to smoke in public, e-cigarettes offer the chance for smokers to switch away from a socially disapproved drug to a more comfortable choice, and our research on the heroin shortage suggests that there is a critical threshold at which people will rush to adopt this new technology. We absolutely need to push the market towards this position, so that as many people as possible adopt a low-harm, low-offensiveness alternative to smoking.
However, there is another huge benefit of e-cigarettes which I think tobacco control advocates need to consider, and which could have a huge impact on the tobacco control movement. To understand it, we need to draw on the lessons of solar power. e-Cigarettes have the potential to drive the tobacco companies out of business in the same way that solar power has begun to put pressure on utility companies through the utility death spiral. This basic model is simple, though disputed: As more and more people install rooftop solar, the utility companies lose money and have to raise prices for their remaining customers, encouraging more to switch to rooftop solar and hastening the loss of customers. This model also applies to e-cigarettes: as more and more people shift to e-cigarettes, tobacco companies will have to recuperate their profits from an increasingly small consumer base, forcing them to raise prices. Fortunately for the tobacco companies their primary production model is incredibly exploitative, so they have a very cheap cost base; but unfortunately most countries now have high tobacco excises, so any cost increase is multiplied to the customer. This will act the way the excise itself acts, encouraging more people to quit or switch to e-cigarettes … and so on.
Solar panels are actually a great market story. Solar power started off as a niche product for satellites, but as companies matured they researched new technologies and became more cost competitive, getting installed in low power applications like calculators and slowly expanding market share. As market share grew the technology became cheaper, and they were able to compete in more and more sectors, until finally now they are able to compete with mainstream utilities. Although the original technology benefited from government projects (especially satellites and space probes) the technology has not itself benefited from subsidies until recently, achieving most of its market share through good old-fashioned market competition and investment. e-cigarettes are similar, having developed through chemical companies in China and slowly expanded into the tobacco market. They’ve been remarkably successful considering the aggressive and anti-market behavior of most tobacco companies, which shows just how unpopular the tobacco product is even amongst many of its regular users. Furthermore, just like solar power, e-cigarettes are now benefiting from the regulatory framework within which they operate. In the past, without any regulatory framework, solar power competed solely on price. But now, with clean air laws and emission standards, solar power competes on these other regulatory aspects, which vastly increases its acceptability. Similarly, where once an e-cigarette would have seemed like a clunky and pretentious toy, it now appears sensible or sophisticated – it enables its user to smoke amongst non-smokers, ensures they don’t disrupt parties or meetings for a break, and doesn’t attractive opprobrium around children. In such a strict regulatory framework it has obvious appeal beyond price; and unlike electricity, smoking is a luxury, a choice, which makes e-cigarettes even more likely to attract rapid uptake.
The implications of this for tobacco companies are terrible, just as solar power is a real threat to utilities. If we allow e-cigarettes unfettered access to the smoking market, leave them largely unrestricted, and reduce taxes on their nicotine, we can quickly force a situation in which tobacco companies are massively undercut by a genuinely disruptive competitor. As tobacco companies lose money they lose the ability to fight court cases against new regulations, and to market aggressively in new markets (such as developing nations). But their only alternative is to raise prices on existing users, encouraging more to switch to e-cigarettes. This is especially problematic for tobacco companies because of their vulnerability to divestment; just this week AXA dumped 2 billion euros of tobacco shares, and encouraged other funds to do likewise. As they lose investors the tobacco companies lose funds to support further expansion, increasing pressure to retain current smokers – who are shifting to e-cigarettes, a product with a diverse corporate background.
Seen in the framework of “disruptive” technologies like solar power, it seems obvious to me what the tobacco control movement’s response should be, similar to that of environmentalists to solar power: encourage changes to the regulatory environment that favour e-cigarettes; reduce barriers to market entry for these products; continue to put regulatory pressure on tobacco companies; advocate laws that prevent tobacco companies from entering the e-cigarette market; and aggressively encourage divestment of tobacco company shares. With this combination of activities, the tobacco control lobby can hasten the end of the tobacco industry, without inconveniencing even a single smoker.
WIN!
May 25, 2016 at 10:18 pm
“From a harm reduction perspective, such a position is completely nonsensical: if we object to a drug, we should do so purely for its health or social effects, not for the simple fact that it is addictive”
Not quite. It is totally valid to object to addictive stuff for the fact it’s addictive and distorts how it’s sufferers behave. The real question is where do we draw the line on addictive behaviour?
For example, either of us would qualify as “addicted” to alcohol by a teetotaller [1], but from a reasonable view point we’re on the acceptable side of of a cost benefit analysis where the benefits granted (e.g. being drunk) exceed the costs.
By contrast, imagine a health consequence free high that you were willing to pay (say) $500USD a week for. This (may) not reduce you to poverty [2], but a cycle of constant cash outflow you can’t avoid for minimal benefit isn’t something society should accept. Because if we do, non-violent mugging by sufficiently attractive people becomes the equivalent to an acceptable “drug of choice”. [3]
The real challenge is: Where is the line drawn?
These costs fall (badly, loosely and too late) under the social effects you mention. I don’t have a good answer, because any such answer should stand up under challenges that modify it be tiny amounts (e.g. “What if it cost a dollar more/less?”) but simple dismissal of the cost is also a choice that needs to be justified. And not one I’d expect you to put forward…
[1] I’m assuming all teetotallers are completely nuts, as that’s the only position that makes sense to me.
[2] I’m not building a budget here. Adjust the cost figure in your head till it’s high, but not prohibitive.
May 25, 2016 at 11:56 pm
I count the effects you describe in the “social effects” in my statement. That’s why I’m in favour of prohibition of heroin (as I have stated before on this blog), because – in addition to the death thing – heroin is extremely socially disruptive, as are its opioid equivalents. I am also not in favour of absolute liberties or absolute free speech, and I think society is right to occasionally reserve the right to punitively interfere in things it disagrees with on social order or moral grounds. It’s my view that a well-functioning society can resolve through public debate to allow things that were once considered a threat to social disorder but actually aren’t bad for anyone (things like homosexuality and casual sex) while continuing to find more effective ways to prevent things that might once have not really been frowned upon but are actually pretty bad (drunk driving, child sexual abuse). In debating any of these issues we have to balance health and social effects against personal liberty and I hope our society gets better and better at this. What I really hope we don’t do is start defining addiction itself as bad, even if the thing we’re addicted to (e.g. coffee) is affordable and completely harmless (or even, as in the case of coffee, likely to be protective against a range of bad health problems).
In fact I think one of the main reasons the tobacco control lobby has been so effective is that smoking is actually objectively disgusting to everyone who doesn’t smoke, which makes it really easy to impose limits on it. Vaping, on the other hand, is not disgusting at all, and even if it was actually as bad for the person doing it as smoking, it would be a lot harder to prevent. This is a reflection of the social effects of the drug, and a large part of the reason alcohol will never be treated like tobacco – because it’s possible to wreck your health with alcohol without ever adversely affecting anyone else; it’s also possible to have fun on alcohol without affecting anyone else.
I also don’t have a good answer on where to draw the line, incidentally. It’s a social question, to be resolved through politics. But my experience in researching heroin tells me that even when we decide someone has fallen on the wrong side of the line, we need to remain socially inclusive and respect them as human beings. Drug policy all too often doesn’t do this. I don’t think tobacco control policy will ever disrespect people as human beings, but there is a risk that if the moralistic prohibitionist side gets the upper hand, they will unnecessarily limit choices in a way that is bad for the campaign to reduce tobacco-related harms. I hope that won’t happen.
May 26, 2016 at 6:10 am
“I also don’t have a good answer on where to draw the line, incidentally.”
“…there is a risk that if the moralistic prohibitionist side gets the upper hand, they will unnecessarily limit choices in a way that is bad for the campaign to reduce tobacco-related harms.”
While reading this paragraph my instinctive reaction was: The best answer is probably “I little less restrictive than you’re really comfortable with.” Because the slippery slope to unrestricted drugs is going to have individual and gradual costs that can (relatively) easily be seen and (hopefully) have policy adjusted. By contrast the slide towards a prohibitionist position is going to give Donald Trump (and his spiritual successors from any side of politics) the tools to stomp on your face for your own good forever.
I’m not sure that’s the right position, but generally having more freedom of choice (including bad choices) than a poll of society wants would probably be a good thing over the term of human history.
May 26, 2016 at 1:12 pm
I agree, and I think in some cases we have seen societies draw back from initial punitive responses (e.g. Australia’s more moderate approaches to cannabis and heroin). I wonder if this fear of going too far is part of the reason that the most stringent measures in tobacco control were only proposed later, and it is usually enacted in stages? Tobacco is a uniquely nasty product that kills 50% of all people who use it, and is also bad for their family, friends, children and the environment – but we never got around to just banning it. I guess that should be seen as a sign that the people active on the issue were following your reaction.
(Or that the tobacco companies were really effective at using civil liberties arguments to distort the legislative framework in their favor – there is evidence in the tobacco papers that they colluded with certain types of political organizations to build up a discursive framework of liberties in defense of their own product – a discursive framework that now also infects climate change and gun control debates, largely to their detriment).
May 28, 2016 at 6:59 pm
Banning something 70 per cent of the adult population use (tobacco in the 50s) or near 90 per cent (alcohol) is never going to work, so I guess a sensible approach was pretty much forced on policy-makers.
What was your contribution to the heroin shortage debate? I was in Customs at the time, and on the InterGovernmental Committee on Drugs. Took a keen interest in it, and had some perspectives from the enforcement side.
May 30, 2016 at 7:47 pm
“I wonder if this fear of going too far is part of the reason that the most stringent measures in tobacco control were only proposed later, and it is usually enacted in stages?”
I’m pretty sure it was just inertia.
June 1, 2016 at 10:06 pm
Peter, I did a little research on the health and social welfare impacts, particularly on injecting drug users. It helped to understand the relationship between prohibition and harm reduction.
Paul you could be right, but I’ve never really noticed the tobacco control lobby being accused of inertia!